セクションⅠ:異なり Welfare Alterity on Religious Alterity―Religious Factors of Income-Redistribution Rate

Haruka SHIBATA(1)(Kyoto University)
Introduction
“How should we redistribute our income?” This question about justice has been considered at least since Aristotle's The Nicomachean Ethics, which discussed “Distributive Justice”(2). Even now, we are facing and arguing this question as follows:
‒ As a global argument, we can give an example on the idea of redistribution proposed by Anthony Giddens in his The Third Way, argued between Giddens and Ralf Dahrendorf (Giddens 1998; Dahrendorf 1999; Giddens 2000)(3).
‒ As a local argument, we can give examples on the “working poor” in the United States (Shipler 2004), the income disparity in Japan (Tachibanaki 1998; Satoh 2004), and so on.
However, in order to consider this question properly, we have to know how we can conduct sustainable redistribution (i.e. how we can keep our redistribution rate stably at the level we once agreed on) in contemporary society. In order to know this, we have to consider a factual question: “What are the main factors which have aff ected the redistribution rate in contemporary society (or, typically, so-called 'developed' countries)?” The ultimate purpose of this paper is to answer this factual question.
Our conclusion will be: “One of the main factors is religious alterity.”
The Results of Previous Studies
In previous studies, the literature on comparative welfare state has detected the factors which affect the redistribution rate of OECDDAC- member countries (i.e. the countries which make it their mission, as “developed” countries, to internationally redistribute their wealth to “developing” countries).
In the literature, the redistribution rate has been measured by:
‒ “social-transfer(4) rate (as a percentage of GDP)”,
‒ “social-security-benefi t rate (as a percentage of GDP)”
‒ “social-security-expenditure(5) rate (as a percentage of GDP)”,
‒ “general-government revenue rate (as a percentage of GDP)”, etc(6);
while the signifi cant factors which aff ect the redistribution rate have been listed as follows (Esping-Andersen 1990; Huber et al. 1993; Firebaugh and Beck 1994; Huber and Stephens 2001; Swank 2002; Brooks and Manza 2006):
‒ “aged-people ratio (i.e. percentage of population 65 years and over)” [whose effect has been estimated to be positive to redistribution rate] (The original source of updated data: OECD),
‒ “GDP per capita” [positive] (OECD),
‒ “unemployment rate (%)” [positive] (ILO),
‒ “union-membership ratio (%)” [positive] (OECD),
‒ “the importance of non-majoritarian institutions (scored 0-8)” [negative (Huber and Stephens 2001: 68-76; Swank 2002: 87)] (Huber et al. 2004),
‒ “direct-investment-outfl ows rate (as a percentage of GDP)” [remaining to be examined on “developed” countries (Firebaugh and Beck 1994: 649)](Swank(7)),
‒ “the cabinet share of Left parties (from 0 to 1)” [positive] (Huber et al. 2004),
‒ “women's-labor-force ratio of the previous year (as a percentage of total labor force)” [positive] (OECD), and
‒ “the cabinet share of Christian Democratic parties (i.e. Catholic parties or Catholic-Protestant-combined parties) (from 0 to 1)” [positive] (Huber et al. 2004),
all of whose updated data are available from the data set of Huber et al. (2004).
Moreover, Philip Manow added, to the above list, “(the importance of) Calvinism” as a signifi cant (and negative) factor of “social-expenditure rate”. This “Calvinism” is a dummy variable which is scored “1” if more than 15% of population belonged to a reformed Protestant denomination around 1960; otherwise “0” (Manow 2004).
To supplement this statistical argument of Manow's, Sigrun Kahl presented the historical explanation about how Christian denominations (i.e. Catholicism, Lutheranism, and Calvinism) have aff ected the customs of poor relief (or poverty relief), and how the said customs have aff ected the redistributive institutions in Western countries (which reproduce people's attitude to redistribution). In short, Catholicism has restrained the secularization of poor relief, Lutheranism has promoted the secularization of poor relief, and Calvinism has restrained poor relief itself (Kahl 2005; forthcoming)(8).
Kahl's historical explanation can be supported by the result of a statistical analysis(9) that indicates that the variable of “people's preference (i.e. positive attitude) to redistribution” is significant (and positive) and more effective to “social-expenditure rate” than the other significant variables listed above except for “Calvinism” (Brooks and Manza 2006).
Remaining Problems
Then, how strong are the eff ects of Christian denominations on today' s redistribution rate? The answer to this question will enable us to fi nd out how we can treat this religious effects and how we can conduct sustainable redistribution in our contemporary society. In order to measure the eff ects of Christian denominations on today's redistribution rates, we have to examine the signifi cance of “Lutheranism” and “Calvinism” at the same time, as well as the variables listed above. However, this examination has not been explored yet.
Purpose
So, the concrete purpose of this paper is to try this examination. Within it, the dependent variable is the income-redistribution rate of “developed” countries which have Catholic, Lutheran, or Calvinist majority in the population. The independent variables are those listed above (including “Calvinism”) plus “Lutheranism”.
We will examine the relations between dependent variable
(redistribution rate) and religious independent variables (“Christian Democratic parties”, “Lutheranism”, and “Calvinism”), and will conclude that these relations have been statistically significant especially since the 1980s, and that the relations are irreversible, successive, probable, conditional, and substitutable.
Data and Methods
For this examination, we analyze cross-section time-series data (i.e. panel data), across the 1960-2000 period, on 17 OECD-DAC-member countries (i.e. “developed” countries) which have Catholic, Lutheran, or Calvinist majority in the population(10) and also whose data are available in Huber et al. (2004)(11). The details and sources of the variables will be described in the next section.
The analysis of these data requires a cross-section time-series analysis (i.e. panel analysis), especially by the estimation with “constant” and “oneway fi xed eff ects”. The reason of this is the following (Kitamura 2005: 59- 80; Sakamoto 2007):
1. There may be some potential independent variables other than those listed above, so we have to introduce “constant” and “fi xed or random effects (of each agent or time)” into the estimation. “Constant” is the regular eff ect detected for every agent (i.e. every country in our data) at every time (i.e. every year) in the estimation period.
2. The samples (or agents) of our data (i.e. 17 countries) were not randomly sampled but completely counted (with nonsampling errors), so we have to introduce not “random eff ects” but “fi xed eff ects”.
3. These potential independent variables should be applicable to our contemporary and/or future society, that is, they should transcend time. So, their “fi xed eff ects” should be not “two-way” (i.e. both for agents and times) but “one-way” (i.e. only for agents).
Now, let k be the number of the listed independent variables (=11), N be that of the countries (=17), and T be that of the years. If N is small enough (like 17 in our data), then, for the estimation with “constant” and “one-way fi xed eff ects”, we can use Least Squares Dummy Variable Model (LSDV), which is formulated as follows:

[dependent variable]it = [constant] + [coefficient1] [independent variable1]it + … + [coefficientk] [independent variablek]it + [idiosyncratic error as the fixed effect of Agent i]i + [remainder disturbance]it for i = 1, 2, …, N; t = 1, 2, …, T, (1) that is, (2)(12) Then, the coefficients are estimated (as ) by making (3) the least. In addition, and are estimated as: (4) (5)
(Kitamura 2005: 4-12, 59-80; Sakamoto 2007).

For this estimation, I used the statistical computer software SPSS 16.0 J for Windows (with Advanced Models), referring to Liu et. al (2005: 174-85, 204-15)(13). In order to examine the temporal change in the eff ect of each variable, I conducted this analysis for each period of 1960-1969, 1970-1979, 1980-1989, and 1990-2000 (so, T=10 or 11).
Table 1 Panel Analyses on Redistribution Rate(14)

Period 1960-1969 1970-1979 1980-1989 1990-2000
Dependent Variable T B tR R T B tR R T B E tR R T E tR R
Constant -4.55 -14.67 -9.78 -30.22 -6.27 10.84 42.46** 21.80** 0.48 -25.38* 12.98* 27.80** 10.25 34.07** 56.29** 27.69* -3.76
Independent Variables Aged People 1.34** 1.80* 2.75* 3.73** 0.95* 0.73 -1.58* 0.36 0.16 2.69** -0.12 -0.43 0.87 -0.93 -2.72** 0.87 1.37
GDP per capita <0.01 <0.01 <0.01 <0.01 >-0.01 <0.01** <0.01** <0.01** <0.01** >-0.01 <0.01** <0.01** <0.01* <0.01** <0.01* <0.01 <0.01
Unemployment 0.24 0.36 0.36 0.27 0.45** 0.29* 0.03 0.21 0.47** 0.24 0.70** 0.28** 0.39** 0.66** 0.51** -0.07 -0.12
Union Membership -0.03 0.02 -0.18 -0.14 0.13** 0.10 0.24** 0.23** 0.17** 0.14 0.09** 0.16** 0.22* -0.13* -0.07 -0.07 -0.01
Non-majoritarian Institutions -0.12 -0.13 -0.87 0.10 0.78** -0.64 -2.53** -1.30* 0.50* 1.29* -0.39 -1.53** -0.19 -0.46 0.30 0.66 0.18
Direct Investment Outflows -0.47 -0.47 2.09 0.78 0.24 -0.36 -2.09** -1.64* -0.15 -0.01 0.09 0.20 -0.03 -0.11 -0.21* 0.02 -0.22
Left Parties 0.02 0.53 -0.51 1.11 -1.05** -1.52* -1.32* -1.46* -0.09 -1.38 -0.32 -0.52 0.35 0.28 0.29 2.17** 3.50**
Women's Labor Force t-1 0.01 0.14 0.19 0.53* -0.03 -0.18 -0.12 -0.17 0.02 -0.06 0.02 0.12* 0.04 -0.20 -0.13 -0.13 0.26
Christian Democracy 1.31 3.63 4.26 7.62* 0.22 -5.86 -2.19 1.59 -3.08** 0.39 -3.42** -2.94* -1.31 3.64 8.61 4.99 19.65**
Lutheranism -4.01 -4.48 7.89 -0.79 -2.55 3.07 11.62** 16.72** -3.73 5.32 5.77** 2.80 9.16 23.81** 33.36** 17.47** 16.13
Calvinism -4.63* -4.39 3.44 -4.24 -5.12* -1.84 14.99 ** 12.95 ** -4.99** -3.47 -6.07** -1.72 -0.13 2.21 -6.64 -8.40 -1.30
Results
The results of our analyses are shown in Table 1, in which:
‒ “T” is “social-transfer rate” (OECD data in Huber et al. (2004)),
‒ “B” is “social-security-benefi t rate” (ILO data covering 1960-1989 in Huber et al. (2004), with the Italian data of 1982, 1983, 1987, 1988, and 1989 corrected by ILO (2001)),
‒ “E” is “social-security-expenditure rate” (OECD data covering 1980-2000 in OECD (2007)),
‒ “tR” is “general-government tax(-including social security)-revenue rate (as a percentage of GDP)” (OECD 2007),
‒ “R” is “general-government revenue rate” (OECD data in Huber et al. (2004))(15),
‒ “Lutheranism” is a dummy variable which is scored “1” if more than 50 % of population belonged to a Lutheran denomination around 1970; otherwise “0” (Barrett 1982)(16),
‒ “Calvinism” is a dummy variable which is scored “1” if more than 25% of population belonged to a Reformed denomination(17) around 1970; otherwise “0” (Barrett 1982)(18),
and the other independent variables are those listed in the section of “The Results of Previous Studies”.
The summary of the results shown in Table 1 are the following:
[1] The eff ect of “aged-people ratio” decayed in the 1970s.
[2] The effects of domestic economic variables of “GDP per capita” and “unemployment rate” emerged in the 1970s and decayed in the 1990s.
[3] The effects of religious variables of “Christian Democratic parties (mainly Catholic parties)”, “Lutheranism”, and “Calvinism” emerged in the 1970s and became stable (in line with Kahl's previously mentioned historical explanation) in the 1980s.
[4] The eff ects of the other variables and constant were only unstable.
As for [3], we should note that there are two positive coefficients (enclosed fi gures) in “Calvinism” row, which are inconsistent with Calvinist poor-relief tradition. But these coeffi cients concentrate in the 1970s, when the eff ects of religious variables emerged. So we can think that the eff ects were unstable in the 1970s and became stable in the 1980s, just as the eff ect of “aged-people ratio” became unstable (i.e. got reversely negative) in the 1990s.
Such stable effects of religion on redistribution rate from the 1980s can be observed visually in Figure 1 and 2, which show the redistribution rates classified by three Christian denominations: the black lines indicate Lutheran countries, the gray lines Catholic, and the white lines Calvinist (and besides the black dots indicate Japan). These fi gures show that, in redistribution rate, three denominational groups had had the same tendency of increase until the 1970s, but they have had different tendencies since the 1980s: Lutheran countries have come to rank higher, Catholic countries have kept to rank widely, and Calvinist countries have come to rank lower.

[ph]
Figure 1 Social-Security-Benefi t/Expenditure Rates Classifi ed by Denominations(19)
[ph]
Figure 2 Tax-Revenue Rates Classifi ed by Denominations(20)

Discussion
Then, why did religion strengthen its eff ect on redistribution rate in the 1970s and the 1980s ([3])? To this question, the results of [1] and [2] are suggestive. According to [1] and [2], the eff ect of “aged-people ratio” decayed in the 1970s, and the eff ects of domestic economic variables (“GDP per capita” and “unemployment rate”) emerged in the 1970s and decayed in the 1990s. These mean the following:

[1+] Until the 1960s, nation-states had been supporting the basic livelihood of all the nation's people regardless of the domestic economic condition ([1]). This can be named “welfare policy based upon classical nationalism”.
[2+] But, in the 1970s, nation-states weakened the said welfare policy, and instead started supporting the basic livelihood mainly of the nation' s people who could contribute to the domestic economy (i.e. labor) as far as the domestic economy could aff ord to do ([2]). This means the decay of classical nationalism in the 1970s. Thus, this can be named “welfare policy based upon domestic economy influenced by the change in nationalism”.
[3+] Moreover, from the 1980s to the 1990s, nation-states weaken the said welfare policy, and instead started supporting the basic livelihood of the nation's people based upon religiously-rooted tradition of poor relief ([3]). This can be named “welfare policy based upon religious nationalism”.
According to Benedict Anderson, classical nationalism(21) (which appeared at the end of the 18th century, because of the developments of capitalism concerning transportation and communication) was the movement which regulated the identity of people into a nationality (which integrated various ethnicities(22)) by establishing a standard language and universal education and by granting citizenship (including the support for basic livelihood, or welfare) to all the nation's people (or everyone counted up in the census).
Nonetheless, since the beginning of the 20th century, especially since the 1970s, the further developments of capitalism concerning transportation and communication enabled people to live transnationally, which, regarding the identity of the people, weakened the importance of nationality and thus relatively strengthened the importance of ethnicity (including religion). In this way, especially since the 1970s, classical nationalism has been disorganized by ethnic (or religious) nationalism. Ethnic (or religious) nationalism is the movement which keeps the identity of people within the context of ethnicity (or religion) and pursues its ethnic (or religious) ideals through the activity of the people in unspecifi ed nationstates (i.e. transnationally)(23) (Anderson 1998: 29-45, 58-74).
According to Sigrun Kahl, each Christian denomination politically maintains its own tradition of poor relief in Western countries (Kahl 2005; forthcoming). Hence, it is thought that ethnicity in Western countries contains Christian denominations, and so ethnic nationalism in Western countries contains a religious nationalism based upon Christian denominations.
Thus, it is thought that, because of the developments of capitalism concerning transportation and communication, “welfare policy based upon classical nationalism” has decayed since the 1970s, and instead “welfare policy based upon religious nationalism” has risen since the circa 1980s in Western countries. [Hypothesis α ]
Conclusions
Therefore, the relations between dependent variable (redistribution rate) and religious independent variables (“Christian Democratic parties”, “Lutheranism”, and “Calvinism”), which are supposed by Kahl's historical explanation, have been statistically significant since the 1980s, and, especially since the 1990s, more significant than other variables. These relations are:
‒ irreversible, successive (because religion can historically form the religiously-rooted tradition of poor relief, and then the tradition can aff ect redistribution rate),
‒ probable (because these relations are only probabilistic at 1% level of statistical signifi cance),
‒ conditional (because these relations are observed only from the 1980s and so seem to depend on the historical and local condition of [Hypothesis α ]), and
‒ substitutable (because, for instance, Japan's redistribution rate is the nearly lowest of those of “developed” countries recently, although Japan's population does not have a Calvinist majority).
Last of all, we may foresee two possible ways in the future. They are as follows:
(1) One way may be to maintain a religiously-rooted tradition of poor relief which is common (or dominant in fact) in each region or nation-state. (Redistribution based upon communitarianism or nationalism)
(2) The other way may be to liberalize (or guarantee the individual's chance for) the choice of redistribution rate. (Redistribution based upon liberalism)
If so, which way will be more sustainable? Considering that religious nationalism will become more and more transnational (and thus transregional) in the future, the dominating power of the dominant religion in each region or nation-state will become weaker and weaker, and so the regional or national redistribution of (1) will become more and more difficult and, eventually, change into trans-regional or transnational redistribution as a case of (2). This means that (2) will be more sustainable than (1) from now on.
In relation to this, we are prompted to ask ourselves how we can liberalize the choice of redistribution rate or how we can conduct transregional or transnational redistribution. These questions in particular still remain to be discussed.
Notes
(1)Student in the doctoral course of Graduate School of Human and Environmental Studies, Kyoto University, and also Research Fellow of the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science. E-mail: haruka_shibata@yahoo.co.jp
(2)“… justice in distributing common property always conforms with the proportion we have described (since when a distribution is made from the common stock, it will follow the same ratio as that between the amounts which the several persons have contributed to the common stock)” (Aristotle, The Nicomachean Ethics, 1131b28-31=1990: 273).
(3)Giddens' Third Way is the way which goes between the high-redistribution way (for equality of both opportunity and outcome) and the low-redistribution way (for equality of only opportunity). So, it is the middle-redistribution way which aims to “maximize equality of opportunity … [but] preserve a concern with limiting inequality of outcome too” (Giddens 2000: 53), to “off er a hand-up, not a hand-out … [, that is,] place a prime emphasis on the labour market” (Geddens 2000: 106), and to “help mobilize their [i.e. the disabled's, the sick's, etc] action potential and reduce dependency” (Giddens 2000: 109). But, according to Dahrendorf, the “Third Way is not about either open societies or liberty,” because it involves “the strict insistence on everyone, including the disabled and single mothers, working” (Dahrendorf 1999: 27). This argument ends up in the question whether we should compel everyone to work or not, which still remains to be discussed.
(4)Benefits for sickness, old-age, family allowances, etc (but not for housing or education), social assistance grants and welfare (Huber et al. 1993: 724; 2004 codebook: 6).
(5)Benefi ts plus administrative expenses and transfers to other schemes (Huber et al. 2004 codebook: 4).
(6)On the other hand, the data of “the effect of redistribution measured by Gini coeffi cient” is too little to analyze in time series (Pontusson 2005: 36, 40).
(7)Duane Swank, “21-Nation Data Set on the Comparative Political Economy of Advanced Industrial Democracies, 1955-1999,” Wisconsin: Department of Political Science, Marquette University, 2002.
(8)According to Kahl (2005; forthcoming) (and Manow (2004) on the timing of social protection programs):
‒ In the Middle Ages, Christians thought that salvation could be attained by good works, such as relieving the poor, who shared the poor image with Jesus Christ and thus whose prayer for the salvation of the relievers was thought to be eff ective.
‒ And, after the Reformation:
[1] Catholics persisted in tradition of good works, so they opposed the secularization of poor relief to conserve the individual and voluntary nature (or the aspect of good works) of the traditional poor relief. Thus, in Catholic countries: [1-1] Both outdoor relief and indoor relief in hospitals continued. [1-2] Social protection programs (i.e. national aid in sickness, unemployment, etc) began late (between the late 1880s and the early 1910s). [1-3] Social assistance (i.e. a national last resort safety net), in some countries, began very late (from the late 1970s) with the system fragmented and ungenerous, while, in the other countries, it has not began yet.
[2] Lutherans thought that salvation could be attained only by faith. So they opposed the tradition of good works and secularized poor relief to eliminate the individual and voluntary nature from poor relief. Thus, in Lutheran countries (including Germany): [2-1] Indoor relief in hospitals which receipt individual donation was restricted into the care for the sick and the weak (from 16th c. Ger. and Den., etc). Outdoor relief was secularized (or conducted by the secular authority or state) (in 16th c. Ger. and Den., 17th c. Swe., etc). [2-2] Social protection programs began very early (between the early 1880s and the mid 1890s). [2-3] Because of the richness of social protection programs, social assistance began late (from the early 1960s) but with the system unitary and generous.
[3] Calvinists thought that salvation could be attained only by God's unconditional election, which was not obvious and thus unpredictable to us until the Last Judgment. Then, the principle of understanding an economic success as the sign of God's election first appeared among the Calvinists in 17th century England, Netherlands, and North American colonies. On this principle, (not good works of poor relief but) wealth is a sign of salvation, and poverty is a sign of damnation. Thus, Calvinists there came to give more priority to multiplying their own individual wealth than to Catholic-like individual voluntary poor relief or Lutheran-like national obligatory poor relief. So, in Calvinist countries: [3-1] Workhouses, where the poor were urged to work, were established earlier than other countries (in 16th c. Eng. and Neth., 17th c. Nor. Amer., etc). Individual donations for outdoor relief and indoor relief in hospitals were forbidden, whereas those for workhouses were allowed (in 16th c. Eng., 19th c. US, etc). Workhouses increased much more than other countries, and some workhouses had been operated until the late 20th c.. [3-2] Social protection programs began very late (between the late 1890s and the late 1920s). [3-3] In order to compensate the lack of social protection programs, social assistance began very early (from the mid 1930s) but with the system fragmented and ungenerous.
(9)This analysis was by Ordinary Least Squares estimation with robust-cluster standard errors.
(10)That is, more than 50% of population belonged to Catholic, Lutheran, or Calvinist denomination around 1970 (Barrett 1982).
(11)These 17 countries are those shown in Figure 1 except Japan, Portugal, Luxembourg, and Spain.
(12)“ ” means “is independent and identically distributed, with the mean 0 and the variance σ 2 (population variance)”.
(13)In the estimation, I fi xed the “fi xed eff ects of agents” at the last (i.e. after “constant” and “independent variables”) in order to obtain the coeffi cients of all the “independent variables”.
(14)Constants and coeffi cients estimated by Least Squares Dummy Variable Model. * p<0.05, ** p<0.01. The coeffi cients of the fi xed eff ects of agents are omitted in this table, because we don't intend to examine these fi xed eff ects.
(15)OECD website explains the diff erence between “tax revenue” (tR) and “revenue” (R) as follows: “Tax receipts of the government sector are defi ned as the sum of direct taxes on household and business sectors, indirect taxes and social security contributions. Non-tax receipts include operating surpluses of public enterprises, property income, user charges and fees, other current and capital transfers received by the general government. Data refer to the general government sector, which is a consolidation of accounts for the central, state and local government plus social security.”
(http://www.oecd.org/document/25/0,3343,en_2649_34245_33702745_1_1_1_1,00.html#t_26, 2008.1.1)
(16)The countries scored “1” are: Sweden, Denmark, Norway, and Finland.
(17)The denominations which were at least partly influenced by Calvinist predestination, that is, Reformed Church, Presbyterian Church, Church of England, Anglican Church, Particular Baptist, Church of Ireland, United Church of Canada, and Uniting Church in Australia.
(18)The countries scored “1” are the same as those in “Calvinism” in Manow (2004), as follows: United States, Canada, Australia, Switzerland, United Kingdom, New Zealand, and Netherlands.
(19)The lines and dots covering 1960-1989 are social-security-benefi t rates, ILO data in Huber et al. (2004) with the Italian data of 1982, 1983, 1987, 1988, and 1989 corrected by ILO (2001), and those covering 1980-2003 are social-security-expenditure rates, OECD data (OECD 2007).
(20)The data is from OECD (2007).
(21)In this paper, according to Anderson's broad wording, “nationalism” means “the movements for political independence (ultimately nation-building) of one's own group”.
(22)According to Anderson, the category of the ethnic was “originally devised a century ago, in a pre-welfare age, to monitor disdainfully the fl ows of immigrants from diff erent parts of Europe” (Anderson 1998: 43). Thus, in this paper, according to Anderson's wording, “ethnicity” means “every (imaginary) group identity which was intended to be integrated into nationality”. Various pre-national group identities, such as “blood”, “culture”, “religion”, etc, can be examples of ethnicity.
(23)As a typical example of ethnic nationalism, Anderson gives the case that a Jewish- American, Jonathan Pollard, was arrested for the espionage for Israel in the United States in 1985. As for this case, we can say that the substantial number of Jewish- Americans who felt sympathetic to Pollard, as well as Pollard himself, acted or judged based upon not so much their nationality as their (transnational) ethnicity (especially religion in this case) (Anderson 1998: 71).
References
Anderson, B., 1998, The Spectre of Comparisons: Nationalism, Southeast Asia and the World, London: Verso.
Aristotle, The Nicomachean Ethics. (=1990, H. Rackham tr., Cambridge: Harvard University Press.)
Barrett, D. B., 1982, World Christian Encyclopedia: A Comparative Survey of Churches and Religions in the Modern World, New York: Oxford University Press.
Brooks, C. and J. Manza, 2006, “Why Do Welfare States Persist?” The Journal of Politics, 68(4): 816‒27.
Dahrendorf, R., 1999, “Whatever Happened to Liberty?” New Statesman, 128(4452): 25-7.
Esping-Andersen, G., 1990, The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, Cambridge: Polity Press.
Firebaugh, G. and F. D. Beck, 1994, “Does Economic Growth Benefi t the Masses? Growth, Dependence, and Welfare in the Third World,” American Sociological Review, 59(5): 631-53.
Giddens, A., 1998, The Third Way: The Renewal of Social Democracy, Cambridge: Polity Press.
―, 2000, The Third Way and Its Critics, Cambridge: Polity Press.
Huber, E., C. Ragin, and J. D. Stephens, 1993, “Social Democracy, Christian Democracy, Constitutional Structure, and the Welfare State,” American Journal of Sociology, 99(3): 711-49.
Huber, E., C. Ragin, J. D. Stephens, D. Brady, and J. Beckfield, 2004, Comparative Welfare States Data Set, Northwestern University, University of North Carolina, Duke University and Indiana University. (http://www.lisproject.org/publications/welfaredata/welfareaccess.htm, 2008.1.1).
Huber, E. and J. Stephens, 2001, Development and Crisis of the Welfare State: Parties and Policies in Global Markets, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
ILO, 2001, The Cost of Social Security (1949-1993) (http://mzes162.mzes.uni-mannheim.de/projekte/coss/main.htm, 2008.1.1).
Kahl, S., 2005, “The Religious Roots of Modern Poverty Policy: Catholic, Lutheran, and Reformed Protestant Traditions Compared,” European Journal of Sociology (Archives Européennes de Sociologie), XLVI(1): 91-126.
―, forthcoming, “Religion as a Cultural Force: Social Doctrines and Poor Relief Traditions,” K. v. Kersbergen and P. Manow eds., Religion, Class Coalitions and Welfare State Regimes, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. (http://www.unikonstanz.de/manow/download/religion_final% 20cup%20manuscript%2027-1-2007.pdf, 2008.1.1), 266-94. (Publication information from: http://www.uni-konstanz.de/manow/index.php?page=herausgeberschaften, 2008.1.1)
Kitamura, Y., 2005, Panel Data Analysis, Tokyo: Iwanami Shoten.
Liu, C., J. Roh, and S. Ishimura, 2005, Statistical Processing for Social Research and Economic Analysis with SPSS, Tokyo: Tokyo Tosho.
Manow, P., 2004, “The Good, the Bad, and the Ugly: Esping-Andersen's Regime Typology and the Religious Roots of the Western Welfare State,” Max-Planck Institute for the Study of Societies Working Paper, 04/3, Cologne: MPIfG (http://www.mpi-fg-koeln.mpg.de/pu/workpap/wp04-3/wp04-3.html, 2008.1.1).
OECD, 2007, Factbook 2007 (http://www.sourceoecd.org/factbook, 2008.1.1).
Pontusson, J., 2005, Inequality and Prosperity: Social Europe vs. Liberal America, Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Sakamoto, K., 2007, “Panel Data Analysis,” J. Tsutsui, H. Hirai, M. Akiyoshi, M. Mizuochi, K. Sakamoto, and N. Fukuda, An Introduction to Econometrics with Stata, Kyoto: Minerva Shobo.
Satoh, T., 2004, Japan as Inegalitarian Society, Tokyo: Chuhou Kouron Shin Shya.
Shipler, D., 2004, The Working Poor: Invisible in America, New York: Knopf.
Swank, D., 2002, Global Capital, Political Institutions, and Policy Change in Developed Welfare States, New York: Cambridge University Press.
Tachibanaki, T., 1998, Economic Disparity in Japan, Tokyo: Iwanami Shoten.